Devaluation of the Birr: A layman’s guide
Prof. Seid Hassan – Murray State University–
Devaluation is associated with fixed or pegged exchange rates systems whose value is not being determined by the normal (free) mechanics of supply and demand. In general, devaluation reflects the existence of serious macroeconomic problems (imbalances) and also reflects weaknesses of the government which is devaluing its currency.
When it comes to Ethiopia, the economic weakness is reflected by several of the resource gaps: the savings-investment gap, the balance of payments gap which in 2009 escalated, total exports and imports amounting $1.657 billion and $7.093 billion, respectively, according to the CIA World Fact book. Ethiopia is also afflicted by other gaps such as a continuous budgetary gap, a skilled human resource gap, a significant agricultural (food security) gap, a dire foreign exchange gap, technology gap and most importantly a good governance gap[1]. By just looking at the solvency issue, that is, the balance of payments and budgetary balance gaps and the alarming foreign exchange shortages, one is led to believe that the birr is overvalued and devaluation is necessary.
Related Article : Devaluation of Birr and it's effect in the economy
When I wrote the popular article titled as the “The Causes of the Soaring Ethiopian Inflation Rate,” a few years ago and suggested that the birr was overvalued, some of my readers were perplexed by such an expression, informing me that I was wrong. They did so partly because they thought I was agreeing with the government that devaluing the birr would serve as a panacea for the structural problems that the Ethiopian economy was facing and partly because they thought the theoretical possibilities were applicable to Ethiopia. All that I was saying was this: using standard economic reasoning and rationales of devaluation, the fact that there is a parallel market (black market) with the birr buying less dollars/euros means that the birr was overvalued. The fact that the government has been facing foreign exchange shortages and is unable to meet the lowest required foreign exchange reserves (which is supposed to be not less than a 3-month import coverage, but the actual coverage at times being less than six weeks of import coverage) and the fact that the IMF has been warning the government that it would face financial difficulties implies that the birr could collapse, sooner or later. Moreover, the fact that even some domestic firms were suspending their operations and unable to import the necessary intermediate inputs from overseas due to the lack of foreign exchange also indicate a balance of payments disequilibrium (that is, the exchange rate between the birr and other currencies has become untenable). It also means that, with disequilibrium in the exchange rate in existence, the government will be unable to carry on its new 5-year “Growth and Transformation Plan.” It is for these already existing realities and inherent weaknesses why I argued the birr was overvalued long ago. I also believed that were it not for the continuous influx of donor assets (estimated to be $3 billion in 2009) and remittances (the National Bank of Ethiopia reporting total remittances just for the first two quarters of 2009 being $1798.8 million), the value of the birr would have been much lower than what it was then and what it is now as well.
Regarding the political aspect of the weakness, in general, devaluation comes as a result of the realities of economic mismanagement and the push (many people like to call it- coercion) by the International Monetary Fund (IMF). In general, a greater portion of a country’s citizens whose government bows to IMF’s pressure is considered to be a weak one. Second, since those firms who are engaged in the production of exportables tend to benefit the most from the devaluation of the birr, it indicates the increasing lobbying power of those firms (groups) which are able to turn policy decisions towards their favor. In the Ethiopian case, given that several of the TPLF- controlled conglomerates organized under EFFORT and REST (in collaboration with Sheikh Mohammed Al-Amoudi’s MIDROC Ethiopia) have seized the state, it is only them who stand to benefit from the devaluation. The fact that powerful elements are able to gear government policies towards their favor in turn reflects the weakness of the government which is supposed to look after for the interests of the country and the general populace.
Conventional Paradigm of and Justification for Devaluation
The economic reasoning behind the devaluation of the birr as a means of improving a country’s trade balance is that a decline in the birr would cause exportables to be cheaper relative to other countries. This would then lead to an increase in the volume of exports, other things equal. With the cheapened birr, imported goods become more expensive thereby leading to an improvement in the country’s trade balance. The expected reduction in the trade balance depends, of course, on the exact amounts of imports and exports, their respected price elasticities and a number of other factors which I illustrate some of them below. [Read the full article, PDF]
Birr pic source Laugh in Amharic Facebook group
Tuesday, November 2, 2010
Positive and Negative effects of Devaluation of Birr
Monday, November 1, 2010
Liya Kebede to act along with Antonio Banderas on $55 million epic adventure Black Gold
Billed as an epic adventure, the screenplay by Menno Meyjes is an adaptation of Hans Reusch's novel The Great Thirst.
Annaud and Alain Godardhave co-written the story.
The deal was unveiled Thursday during this year's DFI.
Shooting began in Tunisia earlier this month and the film will shoot in and around Ben Ammar's Empire Studios in Tunisia, as well as on location in Qatar next year.
Black Gold tells the story of the rivalry between two Emirs in Arabia in the 1930's just as oil is being discovered, and the rise of a young, dynamic leader who unites the various tribes of the desert kingdoms
Warner Bros. will distribute the film in France, the U.K., Latin America and the Middle East.
Universal Pictures International (UPI) will distribute the film in Germany and Spain.
Quinta Communications' Eagle Pictures is handling distribution in Italy.
"I am delighted that the Doha Film Institute will be my partners in bringing this epic story of Arab heroism and nobility to audiences around the world," said Ben Ammar. "When I first tried to make this film over 30 years ago, I could not find any Arab partners who shared my belief that culture and cinema was a priority. Now, thanks to the inspirational vision of H.E.Sheikha Mayassa Bint Hamad Al Thani and her team at the Doha Film Institute, I can see how much has changed and that progress is real."
For the Doha Film Institute, which launched at the Cannes Film Festival this year, Black Goldrepresents the first major international feature film that the organization has been involved with.
Amanda Palmer, executive director of DFI said: "One of the goals of DFI is to support and showcase Arab storytellers and expand the reach of Arab films globally. Since our launch five months ago, we have been looking for film financing opportunities that provide unique educational experiences to Qatari youth, and it was important for us to find a production to film here."
Source: Holywood Reporter
Ethiopia: Ban on distance education lifted
By Binyam Tamene | |
Ban on distance education lifted The Federal Ministry of Education has lifted its ban on distance education, after a one-and-half month long negotiation with private institutions ended last week in agreement. At the end of the last academic year, the Ministry scrapped all distance education programs of both private and public institutions in the country due to quality concerns. This was made through a directive issued on August 26, 2010 and sent by the Higher Education Relevance and Quality Agency to industry stakeholders, including 64 private institutions. Following that, the private institutions, led by Ethiopian Private Higher Education Institutions Association (EPHEIA), were engaged in various negotiations with the education minister “to clear the gray areas” and come to an understanding. The two parties came to an agreement last Friday that lifted the banning of off-campus education and expansion of education programs along with opening new campuses by private institutions. The agreement, however, was made under a condition of the private universities and colleges implementing government policy that forces them to outline their curriculum based on a strict 70 to 30 ratio between natural sciences and technology versus social sciences and humanity studies. Based on the agreement, the private institutions will have a two year period after which they would be expected to fully implement the new curricula. According to Nega Namaga of EPHEIA, the agreement further entails a periodical scrutiny by the ministry before the private institutions graduate their students. “It’s a fruit of a long negotiation and we are happy with the move the ministry made,” said Nega. Based on the agreement, the ministry will lift its sanction of any regular new program, increment of student’s enrolment capacity, setting up new institutions, or even opening new branches for private institutions. Concerning those institutions that have been offering postgraduate studies after entering a special contract with the government, they shall continue to do so under close periodic scrutiny and evaluation. It is only when it gets approved by the concerned authorities that they can admit new students. Training of teachers and health workers, however, remains to be given solely to public institutions as the ministry still doubts the capability of private educational institutions. Nega also pointed out that the Association will acquire its own Quality Assurance body in the future. “We are going to scrutinize ourselves and improve the service given by members of the association, but for that to happen, the government should support our endeavor,” said Nega. The Federal Ministry of Education has lifted its ban on distance education, after a one-and-half month long negotiation with private institutions ended last week in agreement. At the end of the last academic year, the Ministry scrapped all distance education programs of both private and public institutions in the country due to quality concerns. This was made through a directive issued on August 26, 2010 and sent by the Higher Education Relevance and Quality Agency to industry stakeholders, including 64 private institutions.Following that, the private institutions, led by Ethiopian Private Higher Education Institutions Association (EPHEIA), were engaged in various negotiations with the education minister “to clear the gray areas” and come to an understanding. The two parties came to an agreement last Friday that lifted the banning of off-campus education and expansion of education programs along with opening new campuses by private institutions. The agreement, however, was made under a condition of the private universities and colleges implementing government policy that forces them to outline their curriculum based on a strict 70 to 30 ratio between natural sciences and technology versus social sciences and humanity studies. Based on the agreement, the private institutions will have a two year period after which they would be expected to fully implement the new curricula. According to Nega Namaga of EPHEIA, the agreement further entails a periodical scrutiny by the ministry before the private institutions graduate their students. “It’s a fruit of a long negotiation and we are happy with the move the ministry made,” said Nega. Based on the agreement, the ministry will lift its sanction of any regular new program, increment of student’s enrolment capacity, setting up new institutions, or even opening new branches for private institutions. Concerning those institutions that have been offering postgraduate studies after entering a special contract with the government, they shall continue to do so under close periodic scrutiny and evaluation. It is only when it gets approved by the concerned authorities that they can admit new students. Training of teachers and health workers, however, remains to be given solely to public institutions as the ministry still doubts the capability of private educational institutions. Nega also pointed out that the Association will acquire its own Quality Assurance body in the future. “We are going to scrutinize ourselves and improve the service given by members of the association, but for that to happen, the government should support our endeavor,” said Nega. Source: Capital Ethiopia |
Ethiopian food truck coming to your neighborhood.
The guys behind the popular Fojol Bros. of Merlindia Indian food truck have been hinting at a new mobile operation for a while, but kept the details under wraps. The new truck debuted alongside the original on Saturday, so it's a secret no longer: Welcome Fojol Bros. of Benethiopia to the streets of D.C.
As you may have guessed, it serves Ethiopian food. Overseeing the operation is 31-year-old Russell Bailey, a high school friend of Fojol mastermind Justin Vitarello. Bailey and his wife, Lula Habte, are cooking, and both come from culinary bloodlines. His family operated a restaurant and deli in Leesburg when he was growing up, and Habte's mother owned restaurants in her native Ethiopia. In fact, Habte's mother's berbere blend is used in some of the truck's dishes.
Options include siga wot (a spicy beef stew) and a fit-fit variation they are calling sunflower injera salad, which combines small pieces of injera (the flat, spongy sourdough bread used as both utensil and serving surface) with lightly cooked sunflower seeds. The truck offers a number of meatless dishes such as lentils, collard greens, beets and green beans. One Ethiopian staple you won't find on the menu: doro wat. Habte has not yet found an American chicken breed she thinks will do the dish justice.
The sauce-heavy menu items are served over injera, as is traditional, but because street food needs to be eaten out of hand, those come with small squares of pre-cut injera to be used as utensils. An external sink installed between the order and service windows allows customers to wash their hands before they eat.
When the truck officially hits the street on Wednesday, you will be able to grab a plate of injera and two menu choices for $7. The plan, initially, is to have the Ethiopian truck travel alongside its curry-hawking partner. The two trucks are almost identical, which hews to the Fojol Bros. aesthetic.
"We call ourselves a traveling culinary carnival," Bailey says. "But one truck isn't quite a traveling culinary carnival. Now that we have two, we feel like we are really living up to the name."
-- Justin Rude
China to invest in Leather factory in Ethiopia
China’s Xinxiang Kuroda Mingliang Leather Co. will open a $67 million leather factory in Ethiopia on Nov. 24, adding to the billions of dollars already invested in the East African country by China.
Xinxiang financed 55 percent of the project, with the remainder coming from the China-Africa Development Fund, the Chinese embassy in Ethiopia said in an e-mailed statement today.
Chinese investments in resource-poor Ethiopia demonstrate that it is interested in more than extracting raw materials from Africa, Chinese Ambassador Gu Xiaojie said in an interview on Oct. 28. China’s ZTE Corp. lent $1.5 billion in 2008 for Ethiopian Telecommunication Corp. to upgrade its infrastructure, while other companies have helped build hydroelectric plants, the ring-road around Addis Ababa and the part-completed African Union Conference Center.
“Ethiopia is the best example to refute some of the criticism of China being in Africa only for resources,” Gu said. “It has got nothing, but we are coming to their needs.”
Source: Bloomberg.com
The economies of Ethiopia and Uganda grew rapidly right through the crisis
Ethiopia: Controversy of Undervaluation of Yuan
Ethiopia: Undervalued yuan, currency wars and their implications
By Seid Hassan,
Part I. Undervaluation and stylized facts
Introduction
As a result of my recently published article dealing with the devaluation of the birr (Ethiopian currency), some friends of mine and students wondered if the controversy surrounding the undervalued Chinese currency, the yuan renminbi, is similar to devaluation or have the same effect as a devalued currency.
Even though both an undervalued currency and one that is being devalued have two common characteristics, specifically their direction of change (their current values being lower than their previous ones) and both being members of a family of fixed (managed) exchange rate systems, there are significant differences between them. An undervalued currency, just like the Chinese yuan, is one whose value is kept lower than where it should be and its value could rise absent of manipulation. To keep a domestic currency below its market value, the central bank needs to intervene in the exchange rate market more often than devaluation would require.
A devalued currency is one whose value is suddenly downwardly altered (and usually its value never to come back up to its previous position) from its official value by the relevant authorities (the central bank of the country with consultation of political leaders.) Currency devaluation is less frequent and such a measure is taken only when the economic fundamentals of a country are in serious trouble. As a result, the economic and political effects of a devalued and an undervalued currency are also drastically different.
The second reason which prompted me to write this article is the acrimonious debate over the undervalued yuan which escalated after the U.S. House of Representatives voted last September threatening to levy tariffs on Chinese imports unless China allows its currency to appreciate. By delving into this acrimonious debate, I briefly present the methods used to keep the yuan undervalued, the pros and cons of an undervalued currency and its economic implications to its trading partners, particularly the U.S. I am sure that readers will find this issue in particular, and the concept of exchange rates, in general, being interesting and applicable to real life situations.
To briefly represent the recriminations over currencies between China on the one hand, and the U.S. and Europe on the other hand, the latter have been claiming that China intentionally kept the value of its currency undervalued in order to sell more goods at the expense of its trading partners. On the other hand, China claims that U.S. policymakers have no moral superiority regarding the handling of exchange rates since it irresponsibly let its unsustainable boom in housing prices and mortgage lending practices corrupt the balance sheets of the world's financial institutions. China also claims that the Federal Reserve's "irresponsible," loose monetary policy is destabilizing world capital markets. What is the truth and why is the undervaluation issue reverberating without an end in sight?
Some stylized facts about the Chinese exchange rate system:
Before 1994, China had followed different versions of fixed (semi-fixed) exchange rate system. Since the beginning of 1994, the Chinese government decided to peg its currency to the U.S. dollar with an exchange rate of 8.28 yuan to the dollar. The pegging remained until July 2005, the time that the Chinese central bank decided to peg the yuan to a basket of currencies- the U.S. dollar, the euro and the Japanese yen being some of the currencies included in the basket. As announced then, the central bank of China was allowing the value of its currency to be partially determined by supply and demand. The value of the Chinese currency has been rising since then (to about 6.65 yuan per dollar today), even though the appreciation is not enough in the eyes of its competitors such as the U.S. and Europe. For some of the reasons I provide below, this appreciation of the yuan is indeed lower than what it could have been. The pegged yuan is now on a “managed float” system in which the central bank of China intervenes in order to change the direction of its value. China’s competitors and some analysts think that China’s intervention is too manipulative arguing that the managed float is a little too dirty.
Is the yuan really undervalued?
There several things that indicate the yuan has been and continues to be undervalued. For one thing, China has been raking record level of trade surpluses against its major trading partners such as the U.S. Since traders must buy the Chinese currency whenever they want to buy Chinese products, the demand for the Chinese currency must rise, thereby boosting its value. Second, China’s trade surpluses have resulted in a rapidly growing currency reserves for the country. Among other things, large foreign exchange reserves signal financial strength which boosts international confidence for the yuan. Third, China’s economy has been growing at a more rapid rate, with annual GDP growth rates ranging between 8% and 11% per year than those of the U.S., Japan and Europe. This growth should boost investors’ confidence for it currency as well. However, the value of the Chinese currency is lower than what the above fundamentals would indicate, mainly due to the interventions of the central bank of China in the exchange rate market. We turn next to the tools that China uses to keeps its currency undervalued. What are some of the mechanisms that China keeps the yuan undervalued?
There are many ways that a country can keep its currency undervalued, depending on the situation at hand, but some of the options and tools available to China and the ones it is known to have implemented include:
a. Buying dollars using the yuan in the open market in order to keep the demand for dollars high and raise the dollar price upwards relative to its own currency. This increased supply of the Chinese yuan effectively decreases its value. According to economist Peter Navarro, China first sells its bonds at about 4% and uses the revenue to buy U.S. Treasury bonds at about 2%. He says: “China is willing to endure these losses because it views them as a small price to pay for creating new jobs in Chinese export industries, albeit at the expense of American workers.” [ ]
b. Increasing the money supply in order to keep domestic interest rates lower than what they would otherwise be. Lower interest rates increase domestic investment spending while at the same time being less attractive to foreigners who could have wanted to make many by putting their assets in Chinese banks.
c. Preventing Chinese citizens from taking their investments abroad or putting a cap on the amount of foreign assets Chinese citizens could invest abroad. This latter action has the potential to decrease the demand for the dollar (thereby making it cheaper relative to the yuan) while at the same time maintaining or increasing domestic spending. All of these actions depress the value of the yuan while at the same time (artificially) increasing the prices of foreign currencies and/or foreign currency-denominated assets. The effectiveness of such policies depend from country to country but given that the Chinese economy is relatively large and the country sits on huge amounts of foreign currency reserves and surpluses, the effectiveness of the policy could be dramatic.
Many policymakers such as the members of the U.S. Congress also complain about China’s managed (fixed) exchange rate system which they claim to have given Chinese exporters undue advantages. They say that China’s use of a fixed (pegged) exchange-rate system allows it to keep the yuan within narrow trading band while at the same time the values of its competitor’s currencies such as the dollar, euro and yen are being determined in free exchange rate market with minimal or no interventions (or are at the mercy of the free market system).
Part II: The real and potential costs and benefits of an undervalued yuan to Americans
[For an extensive discussion and analyses, the reader can refer to the following one of two studies to the U.S. Congress: or ]
To summarize some of the points made below, even though the Chinese currency is undervalued and the complaints about this undervaluation are valid, the undervalued currency is not the main culprit behind our growing bilateral trade imbalance with China. Rather, it is China’s ability to produce certain products at lower comparative costs than its competitors. The reader will also understand why the complaints made by American and European policymakers about the undervalued Chinese currency have not succeeded so far. For those who may not know, the 1988 U.S. law requires the Treasury to identify and submit to Congress, twice a year, if a major trading partner is manipulating its currency in trying to boost its exports and if a retaliatory measure is warranted. But neither the Bush nor the Obama administration have been hardly successful in ascertaining the negative effects of the currency manipulation on the U.S. In fact, and to the contrary, the Treasury’s Semi-Annual Report presented to the Congress in July 2010 and earlier suggest that China is not a currency manipulator, indicating only that the yuan is undervalued. These studies (reports) are contrary to the political posturing made by U.S. and European authorizes, which in turn should indicate to us that the issue is more complex than what meets the eye. Our trade deficit may indeed be unsustainable and something must be done to rectify the problem, but jumping on the China-bashing bandwagon, just like we did it against Japan in the past, will not solve the problem unless we address the real culprits. It is also important to understand that resolving the bilateral imbalance does not mean that our overall trade deficit will find a solution, for the same trade deficit could be maintained as long as we continue to buy more goods from the rest of the world than we sell to them.
Economic Effects of an Undervalued Currency to Different Group of Americans: in Brief
Consumers: The groups of Americans who benefit the most from an undervalued yuan are the consumers. The undervalued Chinese currency allows American consumers for their dollar to buy more goods than would be otherwise, effectively raising their purchasing power and standard of living. American consumers also benefit from the increased variety brought to the market.
Exporters and Import-Competitors: An undervalued currency has the potential to make China’s exports cheaper and imports into China more expensive than they would be under free market conditions. By giving China a competitive edge, the undervalued dollar puts pressure on American exporters and import-competitors and creates job losses. One should not forget, however, that most of the goods that America imports, such as textiles, toys, furniture, shoes etc, are highly labor intensive products and require fewer skills. China has more abundant unskilled labor, which has become increasingly scarce in America. It is also important to remember that most of the stuff that is being imported from China was already being imported from other countries such as South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore and other countries. On the other hand, the undervalued yuan also has the potential to force American import-competing and exporting firms to work harder and be more innovative and creative, which in the end helps them to be more viable and competitive than they would be otherwise.
Domestic (American) manufacturers, particularly those importing capital (intermediate) goods also benefit from the undervalued yuan. By lowering the cost of their inputs, the undervalued yuan helps American producers to be more competitive in world markets than they would otherwise be.
U.S. Government and the U.S. as a whole – The undervalued yuan also has an effect on U.S. government and the U.S. economy as a whole. America benefits when China uses the surplus of funds that it accumulates and buys U.S. Treasury notes, which have the effect of lowering U.S. interest rates. Since the major cost of investment capital is the interest rate, lower domestic interest rates allow American borrowers, businesses and consumers alike, to increase their spending, which in the end increase the size of the U.S. economy. America also benefits from the flow of capital from China when China and/or its citizens buy our assets.
Finally, it is important to understand that a strong and stable Chinese economy is in the national interest of the U.S. in the same way that a strong and stable American economy is in the best interest of China. Since these two economies have become increasingly interdependent, the destruction one implies the destruction of the other – an important and pragmatic principle well-known in the military circles as MAD (mutually assured destruction.) Jumping on the China-bashing bandwagon and trying to make China a beggar of the world nations is not only counter-productive, it could also be downright dangerous. Emphasizing the point I made earlier, my fellow Americans should note that, unless we understand and recognize the real culprits behind our bilateral or multilateral trade deficits, such as our reckless overconsumption and increasing appetite for cheap products, and the increasing dependence on foreign financial resources to finance our debts, our overall trade deficits would stay the same even though those goods that we currently import from China may not come from that country.
I admit that China (and many other countries) has become too dependent on U.S. consumers. The undervaluation of the yuan could be construed this way, even though it is not the major culprit behind U.S. ills. It is, therefore, in the interest of China to let its currency float. A floating yuan would also ease the inflationary pressure which builds up as a result of China’s economic expansion and increased demand for its products from abroad. On the political side of the issue, China has to understand that the mounting domestic political pressure arising from high unemployment and lackluster economic recovery is making U.S. lawmakers increasingly jittery, forcing them to look for a scapegoat. China’s attempt to flex its muscle by restricting its shipment of crucial minerals to the United States, Europe and Japan shows that the country still in its old militaristic (communist) mentality. China has to understand that its remarkable growth hugely aided by international trade and investments made by its trading partners. China’s bizarre acts (embargoes) show that, unfortunately, the economic benefits of trade to a nation are only fully understood by industrial (grown-ups) countries. It is time for China to act one. Given the consequences, industrial nations need to be careful not to lead us towards a trade war.
Seid Hassan is a Professor of Economics at Murray State University
Source EthioGuardian.com
By Seid Hassan,
Part I. Undervaluation and stylized facts
Introduction
As a result of my recently published article dealing with the devaluation of the birr (Ethiopian currency), some friends of mine and students wondered if the controversy surrounding the undervalued Chinese currency, the yuan renminbi, is similar to devaluation or have the same effect as a devalued currency.
Even though both an undervalued currency and one that is being devalued have two common characteristics, specifically their direction of change (their current values being lower than their previous ones) and both being members of a family of fixed (managed) exchange rate systems, there are significant differences between them. An undervalued currency, just like the Chinese yuan, is one whose value is kept lower than where it should be and its value could rise absent of manipulation. To keep a domestic currency below its market value, the central bank needs to intervene in the exchange rate market more often than devaluation would require.
A devalued currency is one whose value is suddenly downwardly altered (and usually its value never to come back up to its previous position) from its official value by the relevant authorities (the central bank of the country with consultation of political leaders.) Currency devaluation is less frequent and such a measure is taken only when the economic fundamentals of a country are in serious trouble. As a result, the economic and political effects of a devalued and an undervalued currency are also drastically different.
The second reason which prompted me to write this article is the acrimonious debate over the undervalued yuan which escalated after the U.S. House of Representatives voted last September threatening to levy tariffs on Chinese imports unless China allows its currency to appreciate. By delving into this acrimonious debate, I briefly present the methods used to keep the yuan undervalued, the pros and cons of an undervalued currency and its economic implications to its trading partners, particularly the U.S. I am sure that readers will find this issue in particular, and the concept of exchange rates, in general, being interesting and applicable to real life situations.
To briefly represent the recriminations over currencies between China on the one hand, and the U.S. and Europe on the other hand, the latter have been claiming that China intentionally kept the value of its currency undervalued in order to sell more goods at the expense of its trading partners. On the other hand, China claims that U.S. policymakers have no moral superiority regarding the handling of exchange rates since it irresponsibly let its unsustainable boom in housing prices and mortgage lending practices corrupt the balance sheets of the world's financial institutions. China also claims that the Federal Reserve's "irresponsible," loose monetary policy is destabilizing world capital markets. What is the truth and why is the undervaluation issue reverberating without an end in sight?
Some stylized facts about the Chinese exchange rate system:
Before 1994, China had followed different versions of fixed (semi-fixed) exchange rate system. Since the beginning of 1994, the Chinese government decided to peg its currency to the U.S. dollar with an exchange rate of 8.28 yuan to the dollar. The pegging remained until July 2005, the time that the Chinese central bank decided to peg the yuan to a basket of currencies- the U.S. dollar, the euro and the Japanese yen being some of the currencies included in the basket. As announced then, the central bank of China was allowing the value of its currency to be partially determined by supply and demand. The value of the Chinese currency has been rising since then (to about 6.65 yuan per dollar today), even though the appreciation is not enough in the eyes of its competitors such as the U.S. and Europe. For some of the reasons I provide below, this appreciation of the yuan is indeed lower than what it could have been. The pegged yuan is now on a “managed float” system in which the central bank of China intervenes in order to change the direction of its value. China’s competitors and some analysts think that China’s intervention is too manipulative arguing that the managed float is a little too dirty.
Is the yuan really undervalued?
There several things that indicate the yuan has been and continues to be undervalued. For one thing, China has been raking record level of trade surpluses against its major trading partners such as the U.S. Since traders must buy the Chinese currency whenever they want to buy Chinese products, the demand for the Chinese currency must rise, thereby boosting its value. Second, China’s trade surpluses have resulted in a rapidly growing currency reserves for the country. Among other things, large foreign exchange reserves signal financial strength which boosts international confidence for the yuan. Third, China’s economy has been growing at a more rapid rate, with annual GDP growth rates ranging between 8% and 11% per year than those of the U.S., Japan and Europe. This growth should boost investors’ confidence for it currency as well. However, the value of the Chinese currency is lower than what the above fundamentals would indicate, mainly due to the interventions of the central bank of China in the exchange rate market. We turn next to the tools that China uses to keeps its currency undervalued. What are some of the mechanisms that China keeps the yuan undervalued?
There are many ways that a country can keep its currency undervalued, depending on the situation at hand, but some of the options and tools available to China and the ones it is known to have implemented include:
a. Buying dollars using the yuan in the open market in order to keep the demand for dollars high and raise the dollar price upwards relative to its own currency. This increased supply of the Chinese yuan effectively decreases its value. According to economist Peter Navarro, China first sells its bonds at about 4% and uses the revenue to buy U.S. Treasury bonds at about 2%. He says: “China is willing to endure these losses because it views them as a small price to pay for creating new jobs in Chinese export industries, albeit at the expense of American workers.” [ ]
b. Increasing the money supply in order to keep domestic interest rates lower than what they would otherwise be. Lower interest rates increase domestic investment spending while at the same time being less attractive to foreigners who could have wanted to make many by putting their assets in Chinese banks.
c. Preventing Chinese citizens from taking their investments abroad or putting a cap on the amount of foreign assets Chinese citizens could invest abroad. This latter action has the potential to decrease the demand for the dollar (thereby making it cheaper relative to the yuan) while at the same time maintaining or increasing domestic spending. All of these actions depress the value of the yuan while at the same time (artificially) increasing the prices of foreign currencies and/or foreign currency-denominated assets. The effectiveness of such policies depend from country to country but given that the Chinese economy is relatively large and the country sits on huge amounts of foreign currency reserves and surpluses, the effectiveness of the policy could be dramatic.
Many policymakers such as the members of the U.S. Congress also complain about China’s managed (fixed) exchange rate system which they claim to have given Chinese exporters undue advantages. They say that China’s use of a fixed (pegged) exchange-rate system allows it to keep the yuan within narrow trading band while at the same time the values of its competitor’s currencies such as the dollar, euro and yen are being determined in free exchange rate market with minimal or no interventions (or are at the mercy of the free market system).
Part II: The real and potential costs and benefits of an undervalued yuan to Americans
[For an extensive discussion and analyses, the reader can refer to the following one of two studies to the U.S. Congress: or ]
To summarize some of the points made below, even though the Chinese currency is undervalued and the complaints about this undervaluation are valid, the undervalued currency is not the main culprit behind our growing bilateral trade imbalance with China. Rather, it is China’s ability to produce certain products at lower comparative costs than its competitors. The reader will also understand why the complaints made by American and European policymakers about the undervalued Chinese currency have not succeeded so far. For those who may not know, the 1988 U.S. law requires the Treasury to identify and submit to Congress, twice a year, if a major trading partner is manipulating its currency in trying to boost its exports and if a retaliatory measure is warranted. But neither the Bush nor the Obama administration have been hardly successful in ascertaining the negative effects of the currency manipulation on the U.S. In fact, and to the contrary, the Treasury’s Semi-Annual Report presented to the Congress in July 2010 and earlier suggest that China is not a currency manipulator, indicating only that the yuan is undervalued. These studies (reports) are contrary to the political posturing made by U.S. and European authorizes, which in turn should indicate to us that the issue is more complex than what meets the eye. Our trade deficit may indeed be unsustainable and something must be done to rectify the problem, but jumping on the China-bashing bandwagon, just like we did it against Japan in the past, will not solve the problem unless we address the real culprits. It is also important to understand that resolving the bilateral imbalance does not mean that our overall trade deficit will find a solution, for the same trade deficit could be maintained as long as we continue to buy more goods from the rest of the world than we sell to them.
Economic Effects of an Undervalued Currency to Different Group of Americans: in Brief
Consumers: The groups of Americans who benefit the most from an undervalued yuan are the consumers. The undervalued Chinese currency allows American consumers for their dollar to buy more goods than would be otherwise, effectively raising their purchasing power and standard of living. American consumers also benefit from the increased variety brought to the market.
Exporters and Import-Competitors: An undervalued currency has the potential to make China’s exports cheaper and imports into China more expensive than they would be under free market conditions. By giving China a competitive edge, the undervalued dollar puts pressure on American exporters and import-competitors and creates job losses. One should not forget, however, that most of the goods that America imports, such as textiles, toys, furniture, shoes etc, are highly labor intensive products and require fewer skills. China has more abundant unskilled labor, which has become increasingly scarce in America. It is also important to remember that most of the stuff that is being imported from China was already being imported from other countries such as South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore and other countries. On the other hand, the undervalued yuan also has the potential to force American import-competing and exporting firms to work harder and be more innovative and creative, which in the end helps them to be more viable and competitive than they would be otherwise.
Domestic (American) manufacturers, particularly those importing capital (intermediate) goods also benefit from the undervalued yuan. By lowering the cost of their inputs, the undervalued yuan helps American producers to be more competitive in world markets than they would otherwise be.
U.S. Government and the U.S. as a whole – The undervalued yuan also has an effect on U.S. government and the U.S. economy as a whole. America benefits when China uses the surplus of funds that it accumulates and buys U.S. Treasury notes, which have the effect of lowering U.S. interest rates. Since the major cost of investment capital is the interest rate, lower domestic interest rates allow American borrowers, businesses and consumers alike, to increase their spending, which in the end increase the size of the U.S. economy. America also benefits from the flow of capital from China when China and/or its citizens buy our assets.
Finally, it is important to understand that a strong and stable Chinese economy is in the national interest of the U.S. in the same way that a strong and stable American economy is in the best interest of China. Since these two economies have become increasingly interdependent, the destruction one implies the destruction of the other – an important and pragmatic principle well-known in the military circles as MAD (mutually assured destruction.) Jumping on the China-bashing bandwagon and trying to make China a beggar of the world nations is not only counter-productive, it could also be downright dangerous. Emphasizing the point I made earlier, my fellow Americans should note that, unless we understand and recognize the real culprits behind our bilateral or multilateral trade deficits, such as our reckless overconsumption and increasing appetite for cheap products, and the increasing dependence on foreign financial resources to finance our debts, our overall trade deficits would stay the same even though those goods that we currently import from China may not come from that country.
I admit that China (and many other countries) has become too dependent on U.S. consumers. The undervaluation of the yuan could be construed this way, even though it is not the major culprit behind U.S. ills. It is, therefore, in the interest of China to let its currency float. A floating yuan would also ease the inflationary pressure which builds up as a result of China’s economic expansion and increased demand for its products from abroad. On the political side of the issue, China has to understand that the mounting domestic political pressure arising from high unemployment and lackluster economic recovery is making U.S. lawmakers increasingly jittery, forcing them to look for a scapegoat. China’s attempt to flex its muscle by restricting its shipment of crucial minerals to the United States, Europe and Japan shows that the country still in its old militaristic (communist) mentality. China has to understand that its remarkable growth hugely aided by international trade and investments made by its trading partners. China’s bizarre acts (embargoes) show that, unfortunately, the economic benefits of trade to a nation are only fully understood by industrial (grown-ups) countries. It is time for China to act one. Given the consequences, industrial nations need to be careful not to lead us towards a trade war.
Seid Hassan is a Professor of Economics at Murray State University
Source EthioGuardian.com
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)